63. Essay Writing Format, structure and Examples. ‘LIBERALIZATION AND ITS IMPACT ON THE INDIAN ECONOMY’

By | June 26, 2021
images edumantra.net 22

LIBERALIZATION AND ITS IMPACT ON THE INDIAN ECONOMY

INTRODUCTION: The Economic reforms currently underway in India represent both a continuity and a break with India’s post-independence development. Its main objective is to, restore sustained high growth to alleviate poverty and raise the standard of living.

DEVELOPMENT OF THOUGHT: Changes in the policy packages towards deregulation, liberalization and opening, up of the economy were initiated in the late 70s and early 80s but it was not until 1991 that major economic undertaken. The major changes in India’s economic reforms fall broadly, under five heads—industrial, trade, financial, fiscal and monetary. However, these measures of stabilization are not by themselves enough. The main impetus for sustainable economic growth has to originate with efficiency and productivity growth brought about through the expansion _ of investment and exports. Another important aspect to be considered is a large number of people in the country living on the poverty line. To make any reform process socially acceptable a poverty alleviation programme must be built in. In the context of resource constraints, serious thinking has to be done as to the extent and pace of economic reforms.

CONCLUSION: India has to go through a painful period of adjustment before the liberalisation can have its fruitful impact upon the economy. In liberalising the economy the government must not forget to protect the poor and the needs of human development.

 The present bout of economic reforms in India—those started in the nineties—marks both continuity and’ all reak with India’s post-independence development strategy. India’s development, strategy after independence was largely influenced by reservation regarding the ability of the market forces to bring about, on their own, optimum allocation of resources, Thus balancing the country’s two main objectives ‘growth’ and ‘equity’.

A realisation has since dawned on policy-makers, based on India’s own experience and the experience of other countries, that: the domestic economy has now reached a threshold where for better utilisation of resources the benefits of the market forces can be harnessed, by proper market-friendly macro and micro-economic policies helping both in higher growth and more equity. This has initiated a serious debate in the country on our development strategy for opening up, the economy and allowing more market orientation, by removing major Government interventions and regulations.

Since 1977, and especially after 1985-86, the Government has embarked upon a series of economic reforms leading towards liberalisation and deregulation. Subsequently, there has been a significant improvement in the growth rate of the country—from the long-existing, low rate of income growth of 3.5 per cent to an average growth rate of 5.5 per cent and above.

As noted, the changes in the policy packages towards deregulation, liberalisation and opening up of the economy had been initiated in the late 70s and early 80s. These changes were not systematic and were never integrated into an overall framework. According to many economists, these changes were rather slow but not monotonic, until July 1991 when the new Congress Government came to power. Since then the, change in the policy packages have picked up momentum. There have been major changes since July 1991. The present Manmohan Singh led Congress Government came into power in 2004. It has further extended the liberalization policy started in 1991. In its 2004-2005 and 2005-2006 budgets, the government has brought along with almost simultaneous changes in trade and finance announced outside the Budget. These changes are primarily confined to Central Government activities and have not been given any general policy directive to integrate with the overall policy packages of the State Government.

The major changes in India’s economic reforms fall broadly under five heads-industrial, trade, financial, fiscal and monetary. The Government’s key economic objective is to restore sustained high growth which is essential to alleviate poverty and raise the standard of living. In pursuit of these objectives the Government’s reform strategy aims at achieving over the course of the next five years: (1) a liberalised trade regime characterised by tariff rates comparable to other industrializing developing countries and the absence of discretionary ‘import licensing (with the exception of a small negative list); (2) an exchange rate system which is free of the allocative restrictions of trade;(3) a financial system operating in: a competitive market environment and regulated by sound prudential norms and standards; (4) an efficient and dynamic industrial sector subject only to regulations relating to environmental security, strategic concerns, industrial safety and unfair trading and monopolistic practices; and (5) an autonomous, competitive and streamlined public enterprise sector geared to the provision of essential infrastructural goods and services, the development of key natural resources and areas of strategic concern.

It involves taking every step necessary to ensure that the burden of adjustment is fairly distributed and that the very poor are protected. As the first step in this direction, the Government has established a National Renewal Fund to provide a social safety net. The thrust of the reform programme would initially be on easing the country’s extremely tight external payments situation and reducing inflation. In this context, the Government intends to pursue a stable exchange rate policy geared to maintain the rupee constant in nominal terms and to rely on fiscal adjustment accompanied by a tight monetary policy to contain inflation. But this is an initial phase. Stabilisation by itself is not enough. As traditional demand impulses originating from fiscal policy will remain constrained in the next two to three years, the main impetus for sustainable economic growth has to originate with efficiency and productivity growth brought about through the expansion of investment and exports. Underpinning such a path of growth must be a consistent and comprehensive structural reforms strategy designed to promote exports, to improve the relationship between the return on investment and the cost of capital, and to increase the degree competition between firms in the, domestic and external markets so that there are adequate incentives for upgrading the technology, improving efficiency and reducing costs.

The main emphasis of the fiscal policy is to reduce the Central Government’s / fiscal deficit, within the broader context of adjustment of the overall public, sector budget. Reducing the overall public sector budget will require increased financial discipline by the State Government as well, and the Central Government; will encourage the State Government to take steps to improve their financial performance and to streamline the working of the enterprises. In this context, comprehensive tax reform is proposed. It will improve: (i) the elasticity of tax revenue through identification of new areas and increasing the share of direct tax as a proportion of total tax revenue, (ii) a more equitable and broad-based system particularly with regard to commodity taxation and personal taxation, (iii) the removal of anomalies that distort economic incentives and simplification and rationalisation of customs, tariffs, elimination of exemptions as well as a reduction in the average level of tariffs and finally improve compliance of direct taxes and strengthen enforcement. In this context also, the need for rationalisation and reduction of subsidies and for moving to a more objective system of administered price has been emphasised.

 Regarding exchange rate policy it emphasised the adjustment of exchange rate so as to provide a significant real depreciation, to improve export incentives; and international competitiveness. In this context, the Government intended to keep the nominal exchange rate stable by a suitable fiscal and monetary policy.

In the immediate future, to achieve stabilisation, Government visualises a tightening of credit and, monetary policies, free higher interest rates and higher cash reserve ratios. It also proposes, by declining the recourse to financial savings by the Government, a larger volume of supply of domestic credit to the private’ sector.

The Government recognises that trade reform is an essential element for securing supply response to facilitate the overall restructuring of the economy and to restore external payment viability. There are five key medium-term objectives in the Government’s trade policy agenda: (1) The broadening and implication of export incentive measures and the removal of restrictions on exports: (2) The elimination of quantitative restrictions on imports: (3) Substantial reduction in the tariff rates; (4) The decentralisation of exports and imports with the exception Of a few items and finally moving to a foreign exchange system which is free of allocative restrictions for trade. The Government also recognises that the temporary restriction on import which had to be imposed by the Reserve Bank of India needs to be relaxed.

The Government recognised that a major restructuring of the Indian economy, implied by its agenda, will very much depend on the success of its industrial policy reforms. In this context, a large number of sick firms which constitute a drain on the Government budget, with their-unpaid outstanding loans, weakening the financial system, in many cases with the firms closing down leaving their creditors unreimbursed, have to be taken care of. For the restructuring of existing sick and loss-making companies, both in the public and private sector, the Government will review the existing provisions of various laws governing labour: relations, the State and the local government’s role in restructuring regulations governing transfer of land, the procedure of liquidation under the Companies Act and other relevant aspects) The Government is aware that the prerequisite of having a safety net or social insurance scheme is to provide support for displaced workers in the organised sector. The Government’s industrial policy strategy marks a major step forward towards changing the regulatory structure of industries. It initiated major changes, including comprehensive delicensing, the abolition of entry controls related to the MRTP Act and automatic approval of foreign technology agreements and foreign investments, among others. The changes in policies concerning foreign technology and foreign investment will enable Indian industries to forge much more with foreign investors and suppliers of technology that has been possible in the past.

The Government’s ownership of the financial and banking institutions has enabled it to achieve the multiple objectives of mobilisation of resources, integration of the rural population into the financial mainstream, enhancement of availability of long-term loans to all levels of industry and agriculture and increased access to credit to small industrialists, fathers and weaker sections of society, However, there are weaknesses and imbalances. The statutory liquidity ratio and cash reserve ratio levels are high, which implies low return for commercial banks on their funds. This reduces the reserves available to non-priority borrowers and raises their costs in moving to market-based operations of financial institutions. Measures have been taken to strengthen the ‘capital markets, the rates for debentures have been freed, mutual funds have been opened to, the private sector and the full statutory powers are to be given to independent agencies to regulate security markets. The high-level Narasimham Committee had been established to review the structure.

 In line with the recommendations of the Narasimham Committee further reforms of the financial sector will be formulated to increase the efficiency of the financial intermediation. The measures required to meet these objectives would particularly involve a phased reduction of priority lending schemes towards the targetted deserving groups and eventual elimination of the subsidies involved, formulation of prudential norms and standards to guide efforts in the recapitalisation of the banking sector and full decontrol of deposit rates.

 India’s severely constrained budgetary circumstances create both the need and the opportunity for placing greater reliance on the private sector for resources mobilisation and investment. Public enterprises provide many of the basic and critical inputs in India. It is a matter of serious concern that inadequate attention has been paid to improving their efficiency. In the context of public enterprise restructuring, it will be important to assess the social cost involved, with the closure of sick units, and to develop options and measures for a compensation of retrenched labour. Enterprises in areas judged appropriate for continued public sector involvement will be provided with a greater degree of managerial autonomy along with a progressive reduction in budgetary transfers and loans. Sale of selected firms or partial divestment for specific sectors is being increased, pursued.

The Government recognises that adjustment programmes entail a significant transitional cost. This cost includes the potential loss of output, employment and consumption due to the deflationary impact of fiscal consolidation and frictions in the restructuring process which must be equitably borne by all sections of the society.

 However, a large proportion of India’s population continues to be subject to malnutrition and ill health. For this group, the Government is committed to minimising its share of the burden of adjustment. Thus the Government should provide higher outlays on elementary education, rural drinking water supply, assistance to small and marginal farmers, programmes for women and children, programmes for the welfare of scheduled caste and scheduled tribes and the weaker sections of the society, and increased expenditure on infrastructure and employment generation projects in rural areas. Further steps have to be taken to re-allocate social expenditure, particularly health and education for the poor. Additional cost-effective compensatory programmes, particularly in the areas of nutrition and employment, should be strengthened and broadened. In this context, the establishment of a National Renewal Fund has been proposed. Against this backdrop of proposed policy changes, the first set of changes introduced by the Government comprises increasing taxes and reduction in Government expenditure, in order to reduce the deficit. Simultaneously, there have been adjustments in the exchange rates to make exports more attractive and to control imports to narrow the balance of payment gap: Along with this, a tight monetary policy was followed. Subsequent assessments, however, revealed that these measures were insufficient to reduce excess demand for imports. Consequently, the Government imposed emergency credit restrictions on imports. Unfortunately, although the Government took timely measures in the field of trade, industrial policy and fiscal measures, it took a comparatively long time to introduce financial liberalisation measures, public enterprise reform and measures affecting the mobility of labour and capital which are normally known as entry/exit policy.

By introducing all these changes, the Government has been successful in its stabilisation attempts to a certain extent. For instance, the foreign exchange reserve has reached 128.9 billion $ on 4 February 2005, increasing by $31 billion from 2003-04, though it should be realised that this benefit is only a one time gain, resulting primarily from multilateral aids. Thus a major part of multilateral aid has been used for debt servicing. Even NRI outflow which increased $10.2 billion in 2002-03 to $14.3 billion in 2003-04. Thus, net Inflow is still positive. There are differences of opinion as to the potential adverse effect of attaining stabilisation by this method. For example, to reduce the gap the contribution Of export growth has long term stable implications, but resorting to too much import compression, will affect adversely the possibility of export growth, and may prove to be self-defeating, especially if the import component of non-tradition exports is very high.

The 2005-06 budget further has accelerated the reform process by reducing the deficit to 4.3 per cent of GDP but again ‘by a modest increase in revenue and a heavy reduction in expenditure, especially expenditure on capital formation and on human development. For further reduction in fertilizer subsidy, nothing has been worked out.

With regard to the impact of economic reforms on social expenditure and poverty alleviation, it is noted that the reforms have affected public expenditure and many of the key social services areas like health, sanitation, water supply etc. which contribute to the welfare of the poor. It does not mean that there is no scope for economising these expenditures but it implies that it should be done carefully. Any across the board reduction may be politically and administratively easy but would be harmful to the poor.

The essence of the present economic reforms, understandably, is to resort to the market and make price corrections according to the relative scarcity values and rates of returns for all inputs in the productive system. But experience shows that in the long run, when the economy is not growing at a fast pace (i.e., under a contractionary stabilization phase) these price shifts results in the reduction in the reduction in the welfare of some sections of the society while benefiting other sections, both in absolute and relative terms. The fall in real consumption per capita has resulted in a significant increase in the level of poverty ratio and accordingly the number of people below the poverty line. A conservative estimate using Planning Commission methodology and database shows that nearly 6 to 7 million people went down the poverty line during this period. This is a contrast with an annual improvement of nearly 10 to 15 million moving above the poverty line over the last decade. Thus overall, it makes a difference in terms of a setback in the poverty alleviation pace by nearly 20 million, with reference to the trend values. This scenario has high political and social sensitivity. In order to make the reform process morally and socially acceptable and politically feasible, a conscious positive programme on poverty alleviation will be needed. The need for such a programme will be more felt if the message is that the present structural adjustment phase will last for more than 3 to 4 years.

The economic reform process also breeds a class of “new poor”. These are the people who will be affected by the restructuring process through ‘closures’. Many of them are at the higher and middle-income level, mostly in the organised sector and easy to identify. They are the target groups which can be covered by the National Renewal Fund. In this context, it should be noted that already there has been a significant increase in the per cent of unemployed. To provide a cushion to the poor against a high price increase, the Government uses the Public Distribution System (PDS); however, its effectiveness needs to be improved. For instance: (I) The inter-State PDS’s allocation is made on a. per capita basis regardless of income; (2) within a given area the poor-income groups are not functionally the most important beneficiaries of the PDS. In West Bengal, for example, the PDS financed 54 per cent of wheat consumption of the rural highest, income groups; (3) the PDS is grossly inadequate, especially in areas with high poverty intensity. The income of the poor is much too low to take advantage even of the PDS; and finally, the whole approach towards the impact on the vulnerable section of the society should be reviewed in the light of reduced public expenditure on social programmes. For example, cuts in the health programme could lead to an increase in India’s already high incidence of tropical diseases. In addition, a poor education programme has its impact not only on the rural wage of the poor but also in the drive for export growth and adoption of better technology, by making the labour force more illiterate.

The stabilisation package is giving the anticipated results; it has also skilfully combined some of the structural adjustment changes. However, the adequacy of the structural adjustment elements and the growth factors in the stabilization programme of the Government has been questioned by many economists. It is felt that many of the measures taken are on the soil side, as it does not remove any implicit subsidies. In this context, measures to contain the Government wages bill have not been given proper priority. With regard to taxation, it is felt that even now, the indirect tax rates in India, particularly on imports, are very high compared to other LDCs. Of the measures on the adjustment that have been implemented, almost all are in the Central Government sector: whereas substantial fiscal deficit exists in the States, almost close to that of the Centre of nearly 1.8 per cent of GDP. More exhaustive measures need to be taken to curtail the States’ expenditure pattern. With regard to the cut in the capital expenditure, it is rightly realised that there are many wasteful expenditure items in the present composition of public investment. One should, however, be cautious not to reduce them indiscriminately, since in this process, along with the unproductive, the productive sectors, also may suffer a cut.

The ‘exit rules’ constraining firms from liquidating their assets or retrenching workers remain major hindrances to improving their efficiency and new investments in the organised sector. Any postponement of policy in this area does not fit with the bask philosophy of structural reform and efficiency. As to the role of foreign investment, they should be given more open-ended facilities, since even now there remains a large number. of constraints in the form of Government restrictions on remittances of profit, and the Government’s approval required for some major productive sectors. In the field of financial liberalisation, a quicker action is needed on the Narasimham Committee’s Report. Without a sound financial superstructure, the passage to the market system may result in problems, as was observed in the stock market debacle very recently. The financial reforms would strengthen the prudential financial recoveries and allow private banks, foreign and domestic, to bring competition to the financial sector. In the field of agriculture, no specific action has been taken for its betterment. This is the area where coordination with the States sector would be required. The public sector needs greater positive reforms in addition to a reduction in capital expenditure as given in the last two Budgets. The public sector should be allowed to adjust to the new policy frame by focussing on issues like (i) privatisation; and (ii) closure of enterprises that would not survive in a competitive environment.

Finally, although India has successfully diversified and expanded its export base, the major contribution to India’s export growth has come from the demand pull of the receiving countries (especially the developed countries). Only a very small portion can be accounted for by changes in market composition and price competitiveness. Indeed it is only the price factor and a prudent spread over different markets which can help in further increasing India’s exports, in future. This is true especially when the international trade buoyancy does not give rise to much optimism. However, for increasing exports, apart from reducing domestic costs, the country will need better links, with the international market. For this, efficient transport and communication links will be needed to back our trade and investment policy. It is the experience of most countries that in the process of reducing costs and improving the quality of products the role of the literate labour force and skilled manpower should get high priority. Indeed, absorbing higher technology needs a correspondingly well-trained, literate and healthy labour force. In this context the heavy cut in human development expenditure under the recent budget and the low emphasis on domestic R & D (needed to improve the ability to absorb and indigenise foreign technology) are disappointing.

India initiated the process of economic reforms with several handicaps. A high poverty ratio with nearly 32 to 40 per cent of the population living below the poverty line. A very low foreign exchange reserve and level of confidence about India’s creditworthiness. An unfavourable world scenario with its projected low-income growth and increasing regionalism and a substantial loss in RPA trade (Former USSR and Post European countries) for India. India’s hang-up with anti-market socialistic development strategies and people’s shaken confidence arising from unsatisfactory sporadic liberalisation attempts since the 1990s. The existence of a large but inefficient public sector with its own vested interest.

 All these, in the light of inter-country experiences, forewarn of a long gestation period with ‘heavy social costs and raise doubts as to the tolerance level of Indian society for withstanding such less impending social cost.

However, there are plus points: The liberalisation package is preceded by the minimum essential political setup: India’s democratic form of society. In the transformation of the economy into a highly efficient one, moving towards a market economy, India can benefit from her past experience of a mixed economy, Indeed, this places India on a better footing vis-a-vis China, East Europe and other centrally planned economies. India has a very good track record of fulfilling international commitments, with a comparatively low debt service ratio compared to Latin American and some of the African countries. India has a large supply of skilled manpower and cheap labour. India has a reasonably good basic infrastructure.

 It is against this backdrop, that India’s stabilisation measures should be assessed. In the short run, it has fulfilled the specific stabilisation objectives i.e., reducing the balance of payments and the budgetary gaps and recouping all the losses in the foreign exchange reserves. However, a word of caution is needed, from the experience of other countries it has been observed that a short-term success in the stabilisation phase often tempts policy-makers to sit back and prolong the phase of the stabilisation process. In a number of cases, this has led to stagflation. The continuance with too high a foreign reserve ratio (as in India) against a heavy import compression requires a warning. Indeed, a large part of the present problem is due to India’s lack of proper foreign exchange reserve management. This warning is especially needed when stabilisation is achieved through soft option (import and expenditure compressions and heavy foreign exchange borrowings) regardless of the needs for growth and productivity (as observed in a number of other countries). This may retard and render difficult the desired transition to growth. To avoid this, the adjustment process could be slowed down if necessary, especially in certain areas of reform (for example, the rate of decline in the budget deficit as a percentage of GDP). The therapeutic approach of shock treatment in the reform process may not work in India.

 As observed in the case of other countries, a structural adjustment process is much more complex than the stabilization process, and therefore should not be left only with the bureaucrats and politicians. There is no standard recipe for the structural adjustment phase, although there is a fair degree of commonality in the stabilization phase. In choosing proper sequencing a very strong financial and banking infrastructure is a pre-requisite to establishing appropriate market codes of conduct. Therefore financial liberalization should not be postponed for too long. Moreover, in tune with the spirit of present economic reform, decisions on privatization and exit policy should follow early In the game. Although a high rate of inflation is a problem the key issue is to revamp the real growth of the economy by suitable investments and incentives. In the context of improving productivity and international competitiveness, technology improvement should be the buzz word. The attempts to reduce the costs exclusively through fiscal, monetary, financial and trade policies have their limits. Ultimately, it is the technological progress which matters. Imports of technology via foreign direct investment should accordingly feature at the centre as a necessary condition for increasing efficiency. However, the absorption and indigenization of foreign technology alone will satisfy the requisite condition for success. This will be made possible by the growth of research and development in the domestic economy. Reforms, therefore, the research and development policy, must provide a clear strategy and sufficient resources.

To conclude, when Liberalization reforms were initiated the economy was suffering from the heavy foreign exchange constraints and import compression and a relatively unfavourable international scenario but India will have to go through a painful prolonged period of adjustment. Thus, the country must prepare itself to meet this challenge by first protecting the poor and second by protecting the infrastructure and human development needs.

Download the above Essay in PDF (Printable)